Measuring Capital Mobility: A Review of the Feldstein-Horioka Approach

Author(s)

Philip Agyei PEPRAH , Yao HONGXING , Geraude Fortune M. KOUNDE ,

Download Full PDF Pages: 36-44 | Views: 1060 | Downloads: 346 | DOI: 10.5281/zenodo.3491797

Volume 8 - April 2019 (04)

Abstract

In this paper, we present the approach of Feldstein-Horioka on the mobility of capital and analyze the developments that it has evoked over the years.  Though it was developed long ago, the F-H theory has remained very open to different critical approaches that have evolved since Karl Popper's non-naive methodological thinking: the criticism, in parallel with the attempts of consolidation ("immunization") of K Popper. Over the years, these consolidation efforts led this approach to incorporate new econometric methodologies and to partially change its purpose, taking into consideration some external sustainability and other recent factors.

Keywords

Feldstein-Horioka, Capital Mobility, Savings, Investment, External Constraints

References

        i.            Agénor, P.-R., et al. (2003). The integrated macroeconomic model for poverty analysis: a quantitative    macroeconomic framework for the analysis of poverty reduction strategies, The World Bank.         

      ii.            Artus, P. (1992). "Passage à l'union économique et monétaire en Europe: effets sur la croissance et les politiques budgétaires." Économie & prévision 106(5): 123-137.     

    iii.            Azman-Saini, W., et al. (2002). "Financial integration and the ASEAN-5 equity markets." Applied Economics 34(18): 2283-2288.    

     iv.            Banerjee, A., et al. (2005). "Testing for PPP: Should we use panel methods?" Empirical Economics 30(1): 77-91. 

       v.            Bangake, C. and J. C. Eggoh (2012). "Pooled mean group estimation on international capital mobility in African countries." Research in Economics 66(1): 7-17.

     vi.            Behera, S. R. (2015). "International Capital Mobility and Saving-Investment Relationship in the Newly Industrialized Countries." International Review of Applied Economics 29(3): 287-308.

   vii.            Blanchard, O. and F. Giavazzi (2002). "Current account deficits in the euro area: the end of the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle?" Brookings papers on economic activity 2002(2): 147-209.

 viii.            Coakley, J., et al. (1998). "The Feldstein–Horioka puzzle and capital mobility: a review." International Journal of Finance & Economics 3(2): 169-188.

     ix.            Cooray, A. and D. Sinha (2007). "The Feldstein–Horioka model re-visited for African countries." Applied Economics 39(12): 1501-1510.

       x.            Cyrille, S. M. (2010). "Saving-investment correlation and capital mobility in Sub-Saharan African countries: A reappraisal through inward and outward capital flows’ correlation." International Journal of Economics and Finance 2(2): 97-106.

     xi.            De Brouwer, G. (1997). Interest parity conditions as indicators of financial integration in East Asia, Australia-Japan Research Centre.

   xii.            de, S. (2007). "Teza Feldstein-Horioka-jedna mera međunarodnog kretanja kapitala." Panoeconomicus 54(1): 53-67.

 xiii.            Edison, H. J., et al. (2002). "International financial integration and economic growth." Journal of International Money and Finance 21(6): 749-776.

 xiv.            Edwards, S. (2001). Capital mobility and economic performance: are emerging economies different?, National bureau of economic research.

   xv.            Eijffinger, S. C., et al. (1998). "Short-term and long-term government debt and nonresident interest withholding taxes." Journal of Public Economics 68(3): 309-334.

 xvi.            el Alaoui, A. O., et al. (2015). "Linkages and co-movement between international stock market returns: Case of Dow Jones Islamic Dubai Financial Market index." Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 36: 53-70.

xvii.            Feldstein, M. (1991). Domestic saving and international capital movements in the long run and the short run. International Volatility and Economic Growth: The First Ten Years of The International Seminar on Macroeconomics, Elsevier Science Publishers BV.

xviii.            Feldstein, M. and C. Horioka (1980). "National saving and international capital flows." Economic Journal 90: 314-329.

 xix.            Feyerabend, P. (1993). Against method, Verso.

   xx.            Frankel, J. A. (1992). "Measuring international capital mobility: a review." The American Economic Review 82(2): 197-202.

 xxi.            Fu, Y., et al. (2016). "Real interest rate parity in Asian countries: evidence from the quantile unit root test." Applied Economics Letters 23(12): 844-848.

xxii.            Gil-Alana, L. A., et al. (2016). "The Feldstein–Horioka puzzle in South Africa: A fractional cointegration approach." The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 25(7): 978-991.

xxiii.            Goldberg, L. G., et al. (2003). "Has international financial integration increased?" Open economies review 14(3): 299-317.

xxiv.            Grossman, G. M. and E. Helpman (1991). Innovation and growth in the global economy, MIT press.

xxv.            Klein, M. W. (2003). Capital account openness and the varieties of growth experience, National Bureau of Economic Research.

xxvi.            Kraay, A. (1998). In search of the macroeconomic effects of capital account liberalization, unpublished.

xxvii.            Kumar, S., et al. (2014). "Does economic integration stimulate capital mobility? An analysis of four regional economic communities in Africa." Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 29: 33-50.

xxviii.            Lothian, J. R. and L. Wu (2011). "Uncovered interest-rate parity over the past two centuries." Journal of International Money and Finance 30(3): 448-473.

xxix.            Mehra, R. and E. C. Prescott (1985). "The equity premium: A puzzle." Journal of monetary Economics 15(2): 145-161.

xxx.            Obstfeld, M. and K. S. Rogoff (2005). "Global current account imbalances and exchange rate adjustments." Brookings papers on economic activity 2005(1): 67-146.

xxxi.            Özmen, E. and K. Parmaksız (2003). "Policy regime change and the Feldstein–Horioka puzzle: the UK evidence." Journal of Policy Modeling 25(2): 137-149.

xxxii.            Payne, J. E. and H. Mohammadi (2006). "Capital mobility and savings-investment correlations: panel data evidence from transition economies." Applied Economics Letters 13(10): 611-613.

xxxiii.            Pomfret, R. (1997). International Capital Mobility and the Feldstein-Horioka Paradox: Evidence from Settler Economies in the Gold Standard Era. University of Adelaide Seminar Paper.

xxxiv.            Quinn, D. (1997). "The correlates of change in international financial regulation." American Political science review 91(3): 531-551.

xxxv.            Rodrik, D. (1998). "Who needs capital-account convertibility?" Essays in international finance: 55-65.

xxxvi.            Russell, B., et al. (2002). "The impact of inflation and uncertainty on the optimum markup set by firms."

xxxvii.            Sachsida, A. and M. A.-R. Caetano (2000). "The Feldstein–Horioka puzzle revisited." Economics Letters 68(1): 85-88.

xxxviii.            Singh, T. (2016). "Rhetorics of saving–investment correlations and the international mobility of capital: A survey." The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 25(5): 636-690.

xxxix.            Thenmozhi, M. and N. Srinivasan (2016). "Co-movement of oil price, exchange rate and stock index of major oil importing countries: A wavelet coherence approach." The Journal of Developing Areas 50(5): 85-102.

     xl.            Wang, J.-Y. (1990). "Growth, technology transfer, and the long-run theory of international capital movements." Journal of international Economics 29(3-4): 255-271. 

Cite this Article: